Saturday, April 2, 2016

Indian Agriculture: Small is Not Inconsequential

Thanks to the Annual Budget 2015–16, agriculture is once again on the agenda of every discussion about required policy interventions. The signals are clear – the government wants better returns for farmers by linking them to the market and by providing them with better infrastructure. Subsidies, in current form, are likely to go. The shift from subsistence farming to commercial farming is slowly becoming a reality and being considered as the major way out for improving the state of agriculture and farmers in country. The ‘Make in India’ philosophy of the government is encouraging the processing and marketing of agricultural products rather than direct consumption. Increasing marketability is the focus rather than increasing production. However, we, in India still face the challenges of numerical dominance of small and marginal farmers, and access of organized market to those small farmers. 

According to an estimate, more than 99% of the raw materials for industries are being produced by smaller farmers, and 90% of the marketed surplus is being handled by the private sector which, again, is dominated by the not so organized players. Lack of infrastructure, both for scientific production and for marketing of agricultural produce is a well known and well discussed issue.  And only 7% of agricultural produce are processed for further value addition. Now what options do we have by which most, if not all of the existing players in agriculture production and marketing are benefited?
The first answer has been tried in different parts of the country – contract farming. By definition contract farming is forward contract wherein the producer farmer agrees to produce and sell their produce having specified quality at agreed upon price to the processor/middle men/industry.  Unfortunately, in spite of many successful case studies it has failed to meet the market expectations. There could be different reasons however, small size of farms and large number of such farmers have been among the major factors considered responsible for not turning contract farming into a revolution. If successful, it has the potential of removing many limitations of Indian agriculture. 

Second, which is being encouraged by successive governments, is commercialization of agriculture. Commercialization makes agriculture production, processing and marketing riskier.  Seventy five percent of total contribution by agriculture in our GDP comes from the high value products. Higher costs of inputs mixed with lack of skills of using high valued inputs, inefficient processing because of inconsistent supply uniform raw materials, fluctuating prices of raw materials, comparatively less usage of improvised technologies in production and packaging, and challenges in marketing these perishable products with changing customers tastes make it too risky for everyone involved in the process. It can, however, be argued that this is not something specific to India and there have been similar conditions in many other countries. They however, have succeeded. Why can’t India overcome these issues? Unfortunately, assumption that as farmers’ paying capacity increases other supporting services like, information and advisory services, credits and banking, and insurance will cope and meet the farmers’ requirements is misleading one.  Sadly, failure of these services along with all ready dilapidated extension services resulted in series of many unwanted events like, crop failures, demand and price crash of many products, and ultimately farmer suicide. Small and marginal farmers who constitute the majority were the worst sufferers.
Lack of strategic investment in agriculture has been another concern. Although, overall expenditure including subsidies has been continuously rising but the money has not reached where it should reach: where it will have maximum impact. Expenditure because of subsidy on fertilizers, warehouses, cold storages, agriculture implements, are required and welcome but this cannot give us appropriate return on investment unless our farmers’ capacity is built to produce and market their produce efficiently. In spite of the ever spreading network of banks and increasing emphasis on financial inclusion in the country, only 15% of small and marginal farmers have their accounts in banks. Access to credit in most parts of the country is still a problem and dependence on money-lenders or trade middlemen makes agriculture a non-profit venture for most of the small farmers. 
Till now the major focus of removing rural poverty has been on agriculture. However, the country is witnessing changes in consumption patterns both in urban and rural areas. The demand is shifting towards protein based food like, milk and milk products, meat, poultry, vegetables and fruits from that of cereals. These rich food products have better production efficiency, return is higher than that from growing traditional cereals or millet based crops after investing the same amount of resources (manpower and economic). We have a successful cooperative model of Amul, which is not only inclusive but also provides access to market to individual livestock owners. Regrettably, we are not able to replicate the success of Amul for other products. 
Till the time, both, policy makers and the market stop looking at the small and marginal farmers as consumers, and start considering them as the partners, growth in agriculture will remain skewed in favor of large farmers. Although numerically stronger, small and marginal farmers lack negotiating power. Lack of information, resources, and negotiating power render them weaker in agriculture production, processing and marketing system.  If farmers and rural India has to be empowered and a “Make in India” campaign has to be successful, we just cannot then afford to ignore the small and marginal farmers who constitute 80% of total farming population.

****